Skip to main content

Evolution of urban forms observed from space

Abstract

Multiple driving forces shape cities. These forces include the costs of transporting goods and people, the types of predominant local industries, and the policies that govern urban planning. Here, we examine how agglomeration and dispersion change with increasing population and population density. We study the patterns in the evolution of urban forms and analyze the differences between developed and developing countries. We analyze agglomeration across 233 European and 258 Chinese cities using nighttime luminosity data. We find a universal inverted U-shape curve for the agglomeration metric (Lasym index). Cities attain their maximum agglomeration level at an intermediate density, above which dispersion increases. Our findings may guide strategic urban planning for the timely adoption of appropriate development policies.

1 Introduction

Urbanization is driven by the material and social benefits that arise from the size and population density of cities [13]. The tremendous growth of cities may enable poorer countries to develop, eventually reaching the wealth of richer nations. At the same time, the urbanization process causes congestion, environmental pollution, and regional economic inequality. By 2050, nearly 90% of the projected 2.5 billion growth in urban population will be concentrated in Asia and Africa [4]. This makes the sustainable growth of cities in the developing world an issue of significant global importance. Appropriate planning policies based on in-depth understanding of the evolution of urban forms are needed to alleviate the negative effects of rapid growth and maximize its economic benefits. City urban form generally refers to the spatial distribution of human activities within a city, such as places of work and housing density. Far-reaching low-density sprawls and compact high-density cities are two extremes of urban forms that reflect the dominant effects of dispersion and agglomeration, respectively.

Krugman’s core-periphery model [5] and the Alonso–Mills–Muth classic monocentric urban model [610] both attribute the agglomeration of firms and population to the effects of transportation costs on goods and economies of scale. These two primary factors theoretically explain the transition from isolated small settlements to a concentrated core urban area (central business district, or CBD) and its periphery. Original core-periphery models and their derivatives [11] suggest an inverted U-shaped curve for the level of dispersion as a function of transportation costs, where both low and high costs result in high dispersion, but intermediate costs result in agglomeration (low dispersion). Given that the transportation costs for goods have been dramatically declining since the 1960s [12], an inverted U-shaped relationship would imply that dispersion should have prevailed, reducing agglomeration and increasing the sprawl of cities [13]. However, in contrast to the model predictions, many cities have developed a polycentric urban form with a dominant CBD and sub-centres (the number of which scales sub-linearly with respect to population size [14, 15]), suggesting that agglomeration may be prevailing. This should not come as a complete surprise, however, because the service sector has largely replaced manufacturing as the major industry in cities [12, 16], and transportation costs for goods are becoming insignificant in the service economy (3% of the GDP in the 1990s compared to 8% of the GDP in 1929) [12]. At present, it is likely that dispersion is hindered by the costs of moving people instead of moving goods [17], because service firms attribute economic benefits to face-to-face high-information throughput contacts [18]. Indeed, the costs of commuting have been increasing dramatically along with increasing density (see S1 in supplementary information (SI, Additional files 1, 2), Table 2 of [12], and panel d in Fig. 3 of [16]). In this new context of the service economy and increasing costs of moving people, the two competing forces of agglomeration and dispersion are still trying to find their balance point.

The primary purposes of this paper are to understand how agglomeration and dispersion are manifested with increasing population and population density, to study the patterns in the evolution of urban forms, and to analyze if such patterns differ between developed and developing countries. If there is a universal evolution pattern for urban forms, then appropriate and timely planning policies to alleviate some of the negative side effects of urban growth could be developed and applied to developing economies.

2 Results

2.1 Characterising urban forms

Understanding urban forms usually involves the collection and analysis of high-resolution socio-economic [19, 20] and telecommunication data [14], which is costly to acquire and may be outdated. In many developing countries, such data is often coarsely aggregated, infrequently sampled, or unavailable to the public. As an alternative, recent advances in applications of nighttime luminosity data (NTL) provide a free and timely method for the analysis of urban forms. Empirical studies have shown that NTL is capable of mapping local economic activity [2123], so the spatial distribution of luminosity across a whole city can reveal its underlying urban form. In this study, we use NTL collected by the Defense Meteorological Satellite Program’s Operational Linescan System (DMSP-OLS). The data has global coverage with a spatial resolution of 30 arc seconds (approximately 1000 meters of earth surface) and has been released annually since 1992 [21].

The dispersion and agglomeration level of cities can be quantified by the geometric characteristics of a Lorenz curve, a method widely used in economics to quantify inequality in wealth distribution. The curve relates a cumulative share of a variable (income, wealth, or in our case luminosity) to the cumulative share of entities that are characterized by this variable (individuals sorted in the order of increasing income, or geographical areas sorted in the order of increasing luminosity). One of the characteristics derived from the Lorenz curve shape, the Gini coefficient or index, is often used to measure the degree of inequality of urban development [24, 25].

However, two Lorenz curves with similar Gini may describe two different types of inequality: one stemming from a few entities of extremely high value (curve skewed above the reverse diagonal, see a of S2 in SI), and the other from a large number of entities with values just above the average (curve skewed below the reverse diagonal, see b of S2 in SI). To distinguish such situations, a complementary measure that identifies in which direction the curve is skewed was proposed in [26, 27]: the Lorenz asymmetry coefficient (Lasym). When applied to the analysis of urban forms, high Lasym (>1) suggests that agglomeration dominates dispersion, and low Lasym (<1) suggests the opposite. A symmetric Lorenz curve (\(\mbox{Lasym} = 1\)) suggests that spatial human activities are lognormally distributed. This study adopts the definition of [26], where Lasym \(\in ( 0,2 )\).

It should be noted that Gini by itself is not a measure of dispersion. Instead, it is a measure of decentralization [28], because low Gini can indicate two kinds of inequality of urban development: 1) decentralization occurs with intensive agglomeration on local level that leads to polycentric urban forms (see panel a of S3), and 2) decentralization occurs with weak agglomeration that leads to more generally dispersed urban forms without significant sub-centers (see panel d of S3). We retain Gini in our analysis, since the decentralization level might be of significance for wealth creation. In this study, we compute both Gini and Lasym for 233 European and 258 Chinese cities, and validate if a universal evolution path exists.

2.2 Urban forms observed from space

The Lorenz curve and its characteristic coefficients (Gini and Lasym) are constructed over a specific set of entities (here, the smallest areas resolved in a satellite image – pixels with measured luminosity) and are therefore highly affected by the definition of a city boundary. When the boundary is large, the vast dark areas surrounding densely populated regions are included, and both Lasym and Gini may be overestimated; when it is too small (encompassing only brightly lit areas), the Gini may be so low that the city is mistakenly regarded as uniformly developed.

The boundary definition problem is common in urban science, especially in studies of the scaling behaviour of various socio-economic indicators [2, 29]. Generally, two types of boundaries are employed in urban studies: morphological, based on a certain threshold in population density, and functional, based on the density considerations and economic links (approximated by commuter fluxes) between regions unified into a single labor market.

We tested the application of morphological boundaries (in the form of Urban Areas defined by the Census Bureau in the United States) for cities with populations larger than 50 000. The Gini indices for most of these cities are close to zero, indicating uniform development. Therefore, similar to [30], we use a functional definition of a city as a unified labor market, comprising dense urban cores and all suburban areas that have substantial fractions of workers commuting to them. The US, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), and the European Union (EU) have all employed the functional approach to define their city boundaries. However, only the EU boundaries known as larger urban zones (LUZs) have more than one snapshot (2006 and 2010) in the period when NTL data is available, so the urban forms of developed economies are analyzed based on the EU city boundaries in this study. For developing economies, we adopt the urban administrative units (UAUs) of China, which were defined in 2000 and 2010. Gini and Lasym indices are computed by matching NTL data and appropriate city boundaries from the same year.

Figure 1 illustrates NTL distributions and their characteristics for two cities of similar population density within their functional boundaries and with similar Gini indices (additional examples can be found in S3 and S4 of SI). As evident from the luminosity maps, both Brussels and Kirklees have developed multiple sub-centers. However, Brussels’s CBD is much brighter than any area of Kirklees, and the fall-off in luminosity is sharper. The Lasym for Brussels is 1.11, significantly higher than 0.90 for Kirklees, indicating Brussels’s higher agglomeration level.

Figure 1
figure 1

Spatial NTL distributions, luminosity histograms, and Lorenz curves for two cities with comparable density and Gini indices. The data reflects the boundaries defined in 2006. Panels (a), (b), and (c) are NTL distribution, histogram of log-transformed count for luminosity distribution, and Lorenz curve for Brussels, Belgium; panel (d), (e), (f) — Kirklees, United Kingdom

2.3 Universal evolution of urban forms

The evolution of urban forms, or changes in the balance between agglomeration and dispersion, can be observed through Lorenz curve indices expressed as functions of population density. The relatively short history of the NTL data available dictates a cross-sectional approach, where we analyze Gini and Lasym indices for all European Union and Chinese cities (see Fig. 2).

Figure 2
figure 2

Gini and Lasym indices over population density. The blue points represent Lasym, and the red points represent Gini. The regression curve is computed using a piecewise polynomial regression model, and the dashed line indicates the density level where peaks of the regression curve occur

In agreement with [28], decentralization (decreasing Gini) invariably accompanies increases in density, both in developed and developing economies. However, Gini indices of Chinese cities are generally higher than European ones at the same level of density, which means decentralization in the EU occurs earlier than in China. This observation is explained by the simulation model presented later in the paper (see the “Transportation model” section).

The agglomeration level (approximated by Lasym) exhibits an inverted U-shaped profile for cities in both developed and developing economies (Fig. 2). In developed countries, the peak of agglomeration occurs at a density of 189.9 people/km2 in 2006, while in developing ones it is delayed until the much higher density level of 1025 people/km2 in 2000. In agreement with the core-periphery models (Krugman [5] and Alonso–Mills–Muth [610]), agglomeration is dominant at a certain level of transportation cost, proxied by the population density in this study. As illustrated in the supplementary S1, the data on congestion as a function of density in EU cities shows a clear positive correlation between the two, with the median congestion level observed at a density of 240 people/km2. It is noteworthy that this density level is approximately where the agglomeration peak measured by Lasym occurs. Unfortunately, due to insufficient traffic data from Chinese cities, the density of the median of transportation cost cannot be reliably estimated.

A similar inverted U-shaped relationship exists between Lasym and congestion level (measured by Tomtom) in EU cities (see S5). Gini as a function of congestion level is relatively stable (see S5b), contrary to the decreasing Gini as a function of density (S5A). This behaviour may partly be attributable to the differences in definition of metropolitan area boundaries (Tomtom dataset is proprietary and no information on the boundary is available)—for example, Dublin ranks 59th in population out of 233 EU cities but is classified as ‘small’ city in Tomtom, while Lyon ranking 62nd is classified as ‘medium’ city.

We also explore if cities are going through the peak of their U-shaped evolution path during the period covered in the study, i.e., between the two snapshots available in the NTL data. We classify cities as pre- or post-peak (density lower or higher than a threshold) based on the density at which the Lasym maximum occurs in the first snapshot (in 2006 for EU cities, and in 2000 for Chinese cities). Specifically, cities from developed and developing economies are divided as follows: 1) pre-peak cities whose densities are smaller than 189.9 people/km2 for EU cities and 1025 people/km2 for Chinese cities, and 2) post-peak cities whose densities are larger than 189.9 people/km2 for EU cities and 1025 people/km2 for Chinese cities. Accordingly, we produce a scatter plot of differential changes in their Gini and Lasym indices, as presented in S6. Most of the cities have decreasing Gini, which confirms the universal trend of decentralization. However, we do not investigate whether or not decentralization occurs along with agglomeration, which results in two distinctive urban forms, polycentric and extensive sprawls. Additionally, significant fraction of Chinese post-peak cities has decreasing Lasym indices, and pre-peak Chinese cities have slightly increasing Lasym indices. This suggests that Chinese cities are currently going or have recently gone through the peak of their U-shaped evolution path. On the other hand, such a phenomenon cannot be observed in EU cities. This might be caused by the relatively short time span between the two observations in EU cities (4 years compared to 10 years for Chinese cities). To illustrate how cities evolve along their U-shaped path, we randomly select ten Chinese cities from pre-peak and post-peak groups and demonstrate changes in their Gini and Lasym indices over time in Fig. 3. In agreement with our findings, the Gini indices of both groups have decreased between 1996 and 2010 (see Fig. 3c and d), except for a few cities such as Tongchuan, Langfang and Shanwei. However, the Lasym indices of pre-peak cities have shown heterogenous trends (Fig. 3a)–Lasym index of seven cities have increased over time, staying constant or decreasing in others. Importantly, the cities with increasing Lasym expressed a clear inverted U-shaped curve, even though the time when peak emerged varied. For the post-peak group (Fig. 3b), the Lasym of all cities except Guilin have constantly decreased over time. The Lasym graphs suggest most of the cities considered have gone through their inverted U-shaped evolution paths, supporting our findings. However, some cities have not, which requires further investigation in future studies.

Figure 3
figure 3

The changes of Gini and Lasym indices over time for 20 randomly chosen Chinese cities. (a) and (c) shows the Lasym and Gini indices of 10 randomly chosen cities whose densities are smaller than the density at 1025 people/km2 where the peak of the inverted U-shaped curve emerged in 2010. These cities are called the pre-peak cities. (b) and (d) shows the Lasym and Gini indices of another 10 randomly chosen cities whose densities are larger than 1025 people/km2. These cities are called the post-peak cities. Smooth curves are added using black dashed lines

2.4 Transportation model

The common trend for agglomeration to attain its peak value at certain intermediate density (Fig. 2) is observed in cities from both developed and developing economies. However, there is a differentiation in the level of density at which agglomeration peaks occur. The difference is likely caused by the transportation infrastructure that determines costs of moving people. Indeed, China’s considerable investments in transportation infrastructure during the past decades have improved congestion a great deal [31]. These transport improvements were found to efficiently reduce commuting costs [32] and allow further agglomeration of employment in the CBD.

To rationalise agglomeration trends observed empirically through night-time luminosity, we employ stochastic model of a city by Louf and Barthelemy [15], developed to explain polycentric transition that cities experience with growth. Similar to the original model, the city is reduced to the out-of-equilibrium system with two types of agents: households and activity centres. Activity centres are randomly distributed in space on a plane unit circle and households are continuously added to the system cumulatively and randomly. Based on the available choice of potential employment centres households would select particular one with a maximum utility, i.e., attainable wage less the costs of commuting. The model qualitatively and quantitatively explains the emergence of a CBD and transition from monocentric to polycentric urban structure as the population grows. Moreover, it explains the process of some sub-centers eventually losing attractiveness due to the congestion caused by incoming traffic.

To account for the role of infrastructure in shaping urban forms, we modify the city-growth model by Louf & Barthelemy [15] and qualitatively explain how agglomeration is affected by the resilience levels of transportation infrastructure. Following [15], the utility that every additional household is maximising is determined as follows:

$$ Z_{ij} = \bigl[ \bigl( T ( j ) +1 \bigr)^{\beta _{j}} \bigr] - \frac{d_{ij}}{l} \biggl[ 1+ \biggl( \frac{T(j)}{c} \biggr)^{\nu + \beta _{j}} \biggr], $$
(1)

where \(Z_{ij}\) is the net income for a worker living at location i and choosing to work to work at j. The first term \(( T ( j ) +1 )^{\beta _{j}}\) is the maximum attainable average wage paid by firms at j, where \(T ( j )\) is incoming traffic to location that is the numbers of workers choosing to work at location j); and \(\beta _{j} \in ( 0,1 )\) is the scaling factor with a gamma-distribution (\(k\in [ 0.5, 1 ]\), \(\theta \in [ 1, 2 ]\)) with mean ≈ 0.12, suggesting the wages of most sub-centers have an elasticity of 0.12 and only a few areas of extremely high wages [30]. The second term is the transportation costs: \(d_{ij}\) is the Euclidean distance between locations i and j; l is the maximum effective commuting distance that residents can financially withstand, c is the road network capacity, and \(\nu \in ( 1.4,1.5,\ldots 1.8 )\) is the universal infrastructure fragility level for each city, the higher the value the worse the infrastructure the city has. The combined value of \(\nu + \beta _{j}\) is the fragility level to the congestion of location j (see supplementary note 1 for more details of the model). The citywide fragility parameter ν is effectively the sensitivity of sub-centers to congestion-induced increases in commuting costs and associated loss in attractiveness. It controls the capability of a city to sustain agglomeration of employment.

The simulation results are summarised in Fig. 4, with the output of the original Louf and Barthelemy model highlighted in black (L-F model deviates from the empirical observations for Lasym index, which motivated our modifications that we detail in supplementary note 1). In agreement with the observations in Fig. 2, decentralization occurs with growing density and inverted U-shaped curves are emerging. The lower the citywide fragility parameter ν (the more resilient the road networks are), the later the peak in agglomeration level occurs. Cities with high ν have their Lasym decreasing faster after crossing the peak, while the rest maintain their Lasym at relatively high values. As China has invested significantly in transportation infrastructure, we assume that Chinese cities have lower ν, so the simulation explains why agglomeration in Chinese cities peaks at higher densities than in EU cities. The model also suggests that the agglomeration in China can be sustained across a wider range of population density. Notably, the Gini of cities with lower ν is significantly higher than the ones with higher ν at the same level of density.

Figure 4
figure 4

Gini and Lasym as a function of density obtained from the simulation of 1000 systems. Supplementary note 2 discusses the implementation details of the simulation

2.5 Economic effects of agglomeration on wealth creation

The transportation model presented in this study generates inverted U-shaped curves observed in the real world. The fragility of road networks ν affect decentralization levels, the density level at which agglomeration peaks emerge, and the sustainability of agglomeration with increasing density. Given the differences in agglomeration levels observed in cities from developed and developing economies, we want to test how agglomeration and decentralization affect wealth creation while controlling for both density and geographical divisions (eastern EU cities, western EU cities, and Chinese cities).

The linear regression model with GDP per capita as a dependent variable (see Table 1) suggests that both density and agglomeration have a significant positive impact on wealth creation, but decentralization does not (similar to the findings of [19, 33]). While agglomeration and dispersion are regarded as two ends of a continuum, density and agglomeration are so important in wealth creation that policy makers in developing economies are motivated to sustain agglomeration at the highest attainable density, which according to our model makes investment in resilient road networks crucial.

Table 1 Ordinary least squares (OLS) test on GDP per capita for EU and Chinese cities in 2010. Standard errors are shown in parentheses (all non-dummy location variables are mean-centered)

3 Discussion

The emergence of prosperous cities outside of the developed world has allowed developing economies to narrow the economic and social gaps, even though this fast growth poses significant environmental [34] and social challenges [35]. Policy makers from developing countries are learning the lessons that come along with explosive growth, when the lack of understanding of evolution of urban forms can lead to extreme outcomes of failed ‘ghost cities’ [35]. In our study we provide insight into the factors that affect morphology of cities and govern their evolution.

We use NTL to study urban forms in both developed (European Union) and developing (China) economies and conduct spatial analysis of luminosity distributions via Gini inequality and Lorenz asymmetry indices. Our results suggest that there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between the agglomeration and population density. Cities attain their maximum agglomeration level when their density reaches a certain intermediate level. Above this level they experience increasing dispersion. Importantly, this peak agglomeration density varies between different types of economies — 172.6 people/km2 for developed European and 863.3 people/km2 for developing Chinese cities in 2010. We argue, and support this by modelling, that this is a direct result of significant investment of Chinese cities in their public transport infrastructure that increases transportation network capacity and resilience. An empirical study shows that the intensive development of subway network plays an important role in Beijing’s urban agglomeration and new firm formation [36]. Additional ‘last mile’ initiatives (like the dock-less bike sharing schemes) augment the existing subway network. These combined measures eventually alleviate road congestion and help to sustain the high-density city core [37].

The emergence of a peak in the agglomeration level, and differences in the positioning of this peak with respect to population density in different types of economies, may suggest that cities follow a universal path in the evolution of their urban form. Given that high density confers demonstrable benefits of increased productivity, creativity, and wealth (as supported by our regression model), it is important for city planners to understand the evolutionary stage their city is experiencing. Development policies should be timely and consider if the proposed investment will facilitate transition to, or allow maintenance of, the optimum morphology. Conversely, aggressive land development and urbanization well before the agglomeration peak occurs could lead to failure. Therefore, it is not surprising that Ordos, the famous ‘ghost city’ in China which grew much faster than any contemporary and comparable city, is now facing long-term demographic and financial trouble. Considerable investment in building a planned subcenter [38] when its population density was only 270 people/km2 (well below the typical peak agglomeration density value for China) may not have been justified. It will be of vital importance to review construction investments for cities from the developing world to understand to what extent they might succeed and to suggest a more natural form of growth if their current development plans allow for that.

On a practical level, the novelty of our approach is the idea that transport network resilience and capacity is what defines the “peak agglomeration density” (also supported by the EU-China differences in density levels). Additional studies are needed to quantitatively establish the link between the investment in infrastructure and sustainable/attainable density. If such quantitative relationship can be determined, it would allow urban planners to judge whether an investment is warranted, premature, or critically needed.

Even though our study provides empirical evidence of the inverted U-shaped relationship between the agglomeration and population density, we found that Gini and Lasym coefficients were both sensitive to the fraction of zero-luminosity pixels, which generally represent the uninhabited areas, such as water bodies. This study did not exclude NTL data from those uninhabited areas. Therefore, a future study might benefit from using the normalized difference vegetation index (NDVI) of open satellite resources, such as the SPOT-VEGERATION programme, to define the uninhabited areas of a city [39]. Moreover, Gini and Lasym both ignore the spatial features in NTL. Future studies should explore other spatial measures to better understand the U-shaped relationship between the agglomeration and population density.

4 Materials and methods

4.1 City boundaries and census data

The two snapshots (2006 and 2010) of EU boundaries and LUZs were obtained from the Eurostat official page: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/metropolitan-regions/overview. The UAUs boundary of Chinese cities defined in 2010 is available from the National Fundamental Geographic Information System of China. As there is no boundary definition in 2000 for Chinese cities, the computations of Lasym and Gini for Chinese cities are based on the boundary defined in 2010.

Population density and GDP per capita for EU cities are available from Eurostat http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/metropolitan-regions/data/database. The population densities of Chinese cities are obtained from the fifth National Population Census (2000) and the sixth National Population Census (2010). GDP per capita are collected from the China Urban Statistical Yearbook of 2000 and 2010. GDP is further validated compared to the provincial and municipal statistical yearbooks, respectively, and 30 cities of abnormal GDP were excluded from this study.

4.2 Nighttime luminosity data

DMSP-OLS detects nighttime visible and near-infrared radiances and later eliminates background noise (such as gas flares) to produce photographs of pixel values ranging from 0 to 63 to represent city nighttime luminosity intensities. The NTL are available from the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA)’s website: https://ngdc.noaa.gov/eog/download.html. However, the satellite’s onboard sensor only detects radiances between 10−10 and 10−8 under normal operation, so pixels of radiances greater than that are clipped to the value of 63. Therefore, this study adopts the unsaturated NTL, which is computed by combining a limited set of observations acquired at low gain settings with the saturated NTL at high gain settings (available from https://ngdc.noaa.gov/eog/dmsp/download_radcal.html).

Availability of data and materials

All data needed to evaluate the conclusions in the paper are present in the paper and/or the Supplementary Materials. Additional data used in our study, including processed nighttime satellite imageries and the Lasym indices, will be publicly available for research purpose.

Abbreviations

CBD:

central business district

DMSP-OLS:

Defense Meteorological Satellite Program’s Operational Linescan System

Lasym:

Lorenz asymmetry coefficient

OECD:

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

EU:

European Union

LUZs:

larger urban zones

UAUs:

urban administrative units

NOAA:

National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration

References

  1. Batty M (2008) The size, scale, and shape of cities. Science 319:769–771

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Bettencourt LMA (2013) The origins of scaling in cities. Science 340:1438–1441

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Pan W, Ghoshal G, Krumme C, Cebrian M, Pentland A (2013) Urban characteristics attributable to density-driven tie formation. Nat Commun 4:1961

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. United Nations (2014) World Urbanization prospects 2014: highlights. United Nations Publications

  5. Krugman P (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99:483–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Alonso W (1960) A theory of the urban land market. Pap Reg Sci 6:149–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Alonso W (1964) Location and land use. Toward a general theory of land

    Book  Google Scholar 

  8. Muth R (1969) Cities and housing: the spatial patterns of urban residential land use. University of Chicago, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  9. Mills ES (1967) An aggregative model of resource allocation in a metropolitan area. Am Econ Rev 57:197–210

    Google Scholar 

  10. Mills ES (1972) Studies in the structure of the urban economy

    Google Scholar 

  11. Tabuchi T (1998) Urban agglomeration and dispersion: a synthesis of Alonso and Krugman. J Urban Econ 44:333–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Glaeser EL, Kohlhase JE (2004) Cities, regions and the decline of transport costs. Pap Reg Sci 83:197–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Fujita M, Thisse J-F (2013) Economics of agglomeration: cities, industrial location, and globalization. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  14. Louail T et al. (2014) From mobile phone data to the spatial structure of cities. Sci Rep 4:5276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Louf R, Barthelemy M (2013) Modeling the polycentric transition of cities. Phys Rev Lett 111:198702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Çolak S, Lima A, González MC (2016) Understanding congested travel in urban areas. Nat Commun 7:10793

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. McMillen DP, Smith SC (2003) The number of subcenters in large urban areas. J Urban Econ 53:321–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Storper M, Venables AJ (2004) Buzz: face-to-face contact and the urban economy. J Econ Geogr 4:351–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Meijers EJ, Burger MJ (2010) Spatial structure and productivity in US metropolitan areas. Environ Plan A 42:1383–1402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Musterd RCKS, Kloosterman RC, Musterd S (2001) The polycentric urban region: towards a research agenda. Urban Stud 38:623–633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Shi K et al. (2014) Evaluating the ability of NPP-VIIRS nighttime light data to estimate the Gross domestic product and the electric power consumption of China at multiple scales: a comparison with DMSP-OLS data. Remote Sens 6:1705–1724

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Ma T, Zhou C, Pei T, Haynie S, Fan J (2014) Responses of Suomi-NPP VIIRS-derived nighttime lights to socioeconomic activity in China’s cities. Remote Sens Lett 5:165–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Kyba CCM et al. (2014) High-resolution imagery of Earth at night: new sources, opportunities and challenges. Remote Sens 7:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Zhou Y, Ma T, Zhou C, Xu T (2015) Nighttime light derived assessment of regional inequality of socioeconomic development in China. Remote Sens 7:1242–1262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Elvidge CD, Baugh KE, Anderson SJ, Sutton PC, Ghosh T (2012) The night light development index (NLDI): a spatially explicit measure of human development from satellite data. Soc Geogr 7:23–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Damgaard C, Weiner J (2000) Describing inequality in plant size or fecundity. Ecology 81:1139–1142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Gordon P, Richardson HW, Wong HL (1986) The distribution of population and employment in a polycentric city: the case of Los Angeles. Environ Plan A 18:161–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Anas A, Arnott R, Small KA (1998) Urban spatial structure. J Econ Lit 36:1426–1464

    Google Scholar 

  29. Arcaute E et al. (2015) Constructing cities, deconstructing scaling laws. J R Soc Interface 12:20140745

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Bettencourt LMA, Lobo J, Helbing D, Kühnert C, West GB (2007) Growth, innovation, scaling, and the pace of life in cities. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 104:7301–7306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Yu N, De Jong M, Storm S, Mi J (2012) The growth impact of transport infrastructure investment: a regional analysis for China (1978–2008). Policy Soc 31:25–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Venables AJ (2007) Evaluating urban transport improvements: cost–benefit analysis in the presence of agglomeration and income taxation. J Transp Econ Policy 41:173–188

    Google Scholar 

  33. Lee B, Gordon P et al. (2007) Urban spatial structure and economic growth in US metropolitan areas. In: 46th annual meetings of the western regional science association. Newport Beach, CA

    Google Scholar 

  34. (2016) Rise of the city. Science 352:906–907

  35. Normile D (2016) China rethinks cities. Science 352:916–918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Du R, Zheng S (2020) Agglomeration, housing affordability, and new firm formation: the role of subway network. J Hous Econ 48:101668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Fan Y, Zheng S (2020) Dockless bike sharing alleviates road congestion by complementing subway travel: evidence from Beijing. Cities 107:102895

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Shepard W (2015) Ghost cities of China: the story of cities without people in the world’s most populated country. Zed Books Ltd.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  39. Zhuo L, Chen J, Shi PJ, Gu Z, Fan Y, Ichinose T (2005) Modeling population density of China in 1998 based on DMSP/OLS nighttime light image. Acta Geogr Sin 60(2):266–276

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Nick Obradovich (MIT Media Lab) for helpful suggestions and comments on this study. We also thank the anonymous reviewers for their valuable suggestions.

Funding

XL, WX, JD, and SR were supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China, No.41971157.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

HC, YK, XL, IR, and MC conceived of the research question. HC, WX, JD, and SR analyzed the satellite imageries and historical data. HC and YK drafted the manuscript and compiled supplementary information. All authors edited the manuscript and supplementary information and aided in concept development. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Xun Li, Iyad Rahwan or Manuel Cebrian.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Haohui Chen and Yury Kryvasheyeu contributed equally to this work.

Supplementary Information

Below are the links to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary information (PDF 2.0 MB)

Supplementary information (MOV 27.5 MB)

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chen, H., Kryvasheyeu, Y., Xu, W. et al. Evolution of urban forms observed from space. EPJ Data Sci. 10, 27 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1140/epjds/s13688-021-00283-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1140/epjds/s13688-021-00283-w

Keywords